10 found
Order:
  1. Professors and their politics: The policy views of social scientists.Daniel B. Klein & Charlotta Stern - 2005 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 17 (3-4):257-303.
    Academic social scientists overwhelmingly vote Democratic, and the Democratic hegemony has increased significantly since 1970. Moreover, the policy preferences of a large sample of the members of the scholarly associations in anthropology, economics, history, legal and political philosophy, political science, and sociology generally bear out conjectures about the correspondence of partisan identification with left/right ideal types; although across the board, both Democratic and Republican academics favor government action more than the ideal types might suggest. Variations in policy views among Democrats (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   11 citations  
  2.  26
    The man within the breast, the supreme impartial spectator, and other impartial spectators in Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments.Daniel B. Klein, Erik W. Matson & Colin Doran - 2018 - History of European Ideas 44 (8):1153-1168.
    ABSTRACTAdam Smith infused the expression ‘impartial spectator’ with a plexus of related meanings, one of which is a super-being, which bears parallels to monotheistic ideas of God. As for any genuine, identified, human spectator, he can be deemed impartial only presumptively. Such presumptive impartiality as regards the incident does not of itself carry extensive implications about his intelligence, nor about his being aligned with benevolence towards any larger whole. We may posit, however, a being who is impartial and who holds (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  3.  69
    Faculty partisan affiliations in all disciplines: A voter‐registration study.Christopher F. Cardiff & Daniel B. Klein - 2005 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 17 (3-4):237-255.
    The party registration of tenure‐track faculty at 11 California universities, ranging from small, private, religiously affiliated institutions to large, public, elite schools, shows that the “one‐party campus” conjecture does not extend to all institutions or all departments. At one end of the scale, U.C. Berkeley has an adjusted Democrat:Republican ratio of almost 9:1, while Pepperdine University has a ratio of nearly 1:1. Academic field also makes a tremendous difference, with the humanities averaging a 10:1 D:R ratio and business schools averaging (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   6 citations  
  4.  27
    Hume and Smith on utility, agreeableness, propriety, and moral approval.Erik W. Matson, Colin Doran & Daniel B. Klein - 2019 - History of European Ideas 45 (5):675-704.
    OVERVIEWWe ambitiously reexamine Smith’s moral theory in relation to Hume’s. We regard Smith's developments as glorious and important. We also see them as quite fully agreeable to Hume, as enhancement, not departure. But Smith represents matters otherwise! Why would Smith overstate disagreement with his best friend?One aspect of Smith’s enhancement, an aspect he makes very conspicuous, is that between moral approval and beneficialness there is another phase, namely, the moral judge's sense of propriety. With that phase now finding formulation, Smith, (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  5.  25
    The half-life of policy rationales: How new technology affects old policy issues.Fred E. Foldvary & Daniel B. Klein - 2002 - Knowledge, Technology & Policy 15 (3):82-92.
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  6.  13
    Asymmetric Interpretations.Daniel B. Klein - 2002 - Journal des Economistes Et des Etudes Humaines 12 (1).
    Knowledge consists of the triad: information, interpretation, and judgement. Much of modern political economy has miscarried by proceeding as though knowledge were merely “information” that is, as though interpretation were symmetric and final. Economic prosperity depends greatly on new knowledge or “discovery” of profit opportunities that translate into social betterment. These discoveries are often a transcending of the working interpretation, not merely the acquisition of new information. The evolution of interpretations is key to appreciating voluntarism as a maxim for policy. (...)
    No categories
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  7. forthcoming. Narrow-Tent Democrats and Fringe Others: The Policy Views of Social Science Professors.Daniel B. Klein & Charlotta Stern - forthcoming - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society.
    No categories
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  8. Frank questions to discipline your theorizing.Daniel B. Klein - 2014 - In Richard Swedberg (ed.), Theorizing in Social Science: The Context of Discovery. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  9.  17
    Go ahead and let him try: A plea for egonomic laissez‐faire.Daniel B. Klein - 1992 - Inquiry: An Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy 35 (1):3 – 20.
    Thomas Schelling has described how each of us is made up of conflicting impulses. The art of managing these impulses Schelling dubs ?egonomics?. The idea of egonomic calamity underlies paternalism (or, breaking convention, what I call ?parentalism'). The paper argues for laissez?faire in matters egonomic. The rationalizations I give for this libertarian sentiment are old ones, such as accentuating the dignity of the individual and letting the individual learn from example and from his own experience. Also I note, as H. (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  10.  37
    If Government is so Villainous, How come Government Officials don't seem like Villains?Daniel B. Klein - 1994 - Economics and Philosophy 10 (1):91-106.
    At lunch one day a colleague and I had a friendly argument over occupational licensing. I attacked it for being anticompetitive, arguing that licensing boards raise occupational incomes by restricting entry, advertising, and commercialization. My colleague, while acknowledging anticompetitive aspects, affirmed the need for licensing on the grounds of protecting the consumer from frauds and quacks. In many areas of infrequent and specialized dealing, consumers are not able, ex ante or even ex post, to evaluate competence. I countered by suggesting (...)
    Direct download (7 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation